Blog post

Is Europe failing on import diversification?

Despite a goal of economic self-reliance, the European Union’s imports are generally sourced from an increasingly limited set of suppliers.

Publishing date
20 February 2023
A navy charged with containers

In the discussion on European Union strategic sovereignty – the idea that the EU should not be dependent on other economies – there are broadly two approaches. The first is that a certain degree of self-sufficiency (autarky) is needed, at least in ‘strategic’ industries. The second is that strategic sovereignty can be achieved by ensuring that strategically important imports from one country can be substituted by imports from another – in other words, through sufficient import diversification.

But to what extent are Europe’s imports already diversified, and how has diversification developed over time? The European Commission has published two in-depth reviews of EU strategic dependencies and capacities (2021, 2022), identifying 137 products for which the EU is highly dependent on imports, especially from China. These products are mostly in the energy-intensive, health and tech industries. Overall, however, the reviews found that extra-EU trade is diversified and the level of import concentration has remained stable over the last decade. While this may be true for aggregate imports, our analysis suggests it underplays the extent to which imports in several sectors have become more concentrated over time.

For a deeper look at current trends, and to draw out the role of China, we examined import data for 6887 products imported by the EU between 2001 and 2022. We used an indicator of import diversification (the Herfindahl-Hirschman-Index (HHI); see the annex for details) to assess which products are imported from many countries, and which are imported from only a few. The Commission’s in-depth reviews focused on trends for aggregate imports and only carried out a more detailed analysis for a single year and for a limited selection of products. We provide a more detailed analysis for the entire period, by breaking down the data by industry, technology and end-use, and constructing two alternative indicators to highlight the specific role of China in the concentration of EU imports.

Overall, we see big differences in the extent to which products are concentrated in certain countries. For some products (eg vegetable seeds in 2022) EU imports are very diversified, while other products are only sourced from one country (eg 2022 imports of sulphur dichloride from India).

Figure 1 plots the average concentration level for European imports between 2001 and 2022, with a higher number indicating greater concentration of imports among certain exporting countries. Interestingly, despite the surge in globalisation that involved more countries in international trade in the past decades, EU imports became substantially more concentrated in a smaller number of countries between 2001 and 2016, with the level of concentration slightly receding since.

 

Source: Bruegel based on Eurostat. Note: weighted by respective import volumes for the entire period. See the annex for an explanation of the indicator.

One explanation for the increasing concentration of import sources for many products is that it has been driven by the rise of China. To test this, we calculated two alternative indicators: one in which imports from China are assumed to zero but the overall volume of EU imports is assumed to be the same, with imports from other countries scaled up in line with their current market shares to fill the Chinese gap, and one in which imports from China are ignored completely (ie Chinese imports are zero while imports of other countries remain unchanged; as a result of the overall smaller import market, the market share of other countries’ imports increases).

The actual and alternative concentration indicators start at very similar levels in 2001, but as China’s share of European imports increased, concentration increased significantly based on the actual data, but not for the alternative indicators with China stripped out. For the first alternative indicator, concentration drops (Figure 2, left panel), because China is assumed to have been replaced as a supplier by an infinite number of small exporters.

Surprisingly, the second alternative indicator (Figure 2, right panel) also shows a lower than actual level of concentration. That is, imports of goods from countries other than China would be more diversified, despite the assumed reduction in market size, possibly as a result of new exporters competing with old exporters for the European market.

 

Source: Bruegel based on Eurostat.

Critical resources

The EU discussion on strategic autonomy focuses on specific product categories considered critical for security, safety, health and technology. These are in particular strategic resources and basic materials, and certain high-tech items (especially chips and batteries). Assessment of the level of import diversification for different product categories shows significantly varying results. The level of diversification is healthy for most resource-based product categories, with the surprising exception of foodstuff (Figure 3, left panel). For example, imports of fuel products are the most diversified. Imports of manufacturing products, however, are much more concentrated (Figure 3, right panel). Machinery and transport equipment imports seem to drive the overall level of concentration of European imports (Figure 1).

 

Source: Bruegel based on Eurostat.

Import diversification has decreased for more technology-intensive manufacturing products. This is especially true in the high-tech sector, where the increase in concentration over the past decade has been greater than for other types of manufacturing products (Figure 4, left panel). Reliance on a few importers implies less resilience to supply-chain disruptions, and possibly higher mark-ups on imports of potentially crucial components. The right panel of Figure 4 shows that import concentration has increased significantly for final goods, while it remained largely stable for intermediate goods, suggesting relative resilience of supply chains for the production of final goods in Europe.

 

Source: Bruegel based on Eurostat.

In summary, Europe’s imports are generally sourced from an increasingly concentrated set of exporters. China has played a driving role in this development. While this trend has reversed in some industries in recent years, manufacturing imports – especially high-tech imports – remain at a high level of concentration. This development is driven by final rather than intermediate goods. Since high import concentration threatens resilience and worsens European terms of trade through higher mark-ups, tools that encourage greater import diversification should be employed to reverse the trend.

Annex

Our indicator of import concentration is taken from competition policy – the Herfindahl-Hirschman-Index (HHI). This is computed as the sum of squared market shares within a product category, and ranges from zero, signifying perfect competition (in the case of only 150 export countries the minimum is 0.007), to 1, meaning the EU buys a certain product from a single country. An HHI above 0.25 is considered in the economic literature as an indication of high concentration. The European Commission’s analysis covered a limited range of products with an HHI higher than 0.4.

The diversity of intra-EU trade does not factor into our analysis. Likewise, product codes declared confidential by individual countries are excluded, as they would present ‘artificial’ categories for the respective countries and likely bias the results.

The 6887 products we analysed are at HS 6-digit level. Products categories are based on the SITC and rely on Eurostat conversion tables. End-use categories are based on OECD conversion tables.

About the authors

  • Lennard Welslau

    Lennard is a Research analyst at Bruegel. His research interests lie in the fields of macroeconomics, international economics, and data science. He studied Philosophy, Politics and Economics in Freiburg and Buenos Aires and holds an MSc in Economics from the University of Copenhagen. In his thesis, he used a small open economy heterogeneous agent New Keynesian (HANK) model to investigate the role of wage flexibility in countries facing external demand and interest rate shocks.

    Prior to joining Bruegel, he worked as a trainee with the European Central Bank, held research assistant positions at the Walter Eucken Institute and the Copenhagen Business School, and contributed to the work of the UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) as a research consultant, working on empirical trade modelling.

    Lennard is a native German speaker and is fluent in English and Spanish.

  • Georg Zachmann

    Georg Zachmann is a Senior Fellow at Bruegel, where he has worked since 2009 on energy and climate policy. His work focuses on regional and distributional impacts of decarbonisation, the analysis and design of carbon, gas and electricity markets, and EU energy and climate policies. Previously, he worked at the German Ministry of Finance, the German Institute for Economic Research in Berlin, the energy think tank LARSEN in Paris, and the policy consultancy Berlin Economics.

Related content

Dataset

European natural gas imports

This dataset aggregates daily data on European natural gas import flows and storage levels.

Georg Zachmann, Ben McWilliams, Ugnė Keliauskaitė and Giovanni Sgaravatti