Blog Post

Blogs review: Revisiting the case for rational expectations

What’s at stake: The debate about what determines the expectations of economic agents and what model of expectations to use in macroeconomic models has been central to economics since the 1970s. Rational expectations, equal to the statistical expected values of the variables in question, opposed to adaptive expectations that are determined by past observations of the variables, were a central component of the New Classical critique of Keynesian economics and the debate has been active ever since. Recently, a post by Lars Syll, in which he attacks Simon Wren-Lewis for his continued defence of rational expectations, has provoked a reaction by Wren-Lewis, sparking a debate involving heterodox and mainstream economists.

By: Date: November 14, 2013 Topic: Global Economics & Governance

What’s at stake: The debate about what determines the expectations of economic agents and what model of expectations to use in macroeconomic models has been central to economics since the 1970s. Rational expectations, equal to the statistical expected values of the variables in question, opposed to adaptive expectations that are determined by past observations of the variables, were a central component of the New Classical critique of Keynesian economics and the debate has been active ever since. Recently, a post by Lars Syll, in which he attacks Simon Wren-Lewis for his continued defence of rational expectations, has provoked a reaction by Wren-Lewis, sparking a debate involving heterodox and mainstream economists.

The importance of past and present information

Lars P Syll argues that Rational Expectations could only apply to a fictitious, ergodic world governed by stable and stationary stochastic processes. In the real world, however, the future is to a large extent unknowable and uncertain. Structural breaks and regime shifts occur, time and history matter. Events may not be caused by time-invariant stochastic processes with stable probability distributions. Under those circumstances, it is quite possible for agents to make mistakes that turn out to be systematic.

Simon Wren-Lewis writes that if he were to focus in detail on how expectations were formed and adjusted, he would turn to the large mainstream literature on learning. The validity of macroeconomic ideas should be checked within realistic learning environments. However, for modelling purposes, more simplicity is required. One essentially has the binary choice between rational expectations or naive agents with something like adaptive expectations. The problem with adaptive expectations is that they come down to assuming that expectations depend solely on past observations, without regard for monetary policy and the current state of the economy.  Given the importance of decisions based on expectations, that seems too simplistic.

Robert Waldmann finds it obvious that it is better to assume adaptive than rational expectations when attempting to model advanced industrial economies and to guide policy. It is plainly true that most economic agents in the USA quite clearly ignore what economists and the media say about inflation. And under naive expectations, irrational speculative bubbles will arise, in which agents assume some asset price will increase because it has in the past. That is consistent with the data (but the data can also be reconciled with the rational expectations assumption. The problem is – any data can be reconciled with it: It is not a falsifiable theory).

In an older article, David Levine writes that he does not think there are viable alternatives to rational expectations in economics despite the resultant inability to predict crises. This “uncertainty principle” in economics is due to the fact that under any form of expectations other than rational expectations, a theory built on those expectations would be wrong once people start to believe and act upon it (this is essentially the Lucas critique).

Simplicity in models and agents’ behaviour

Simon Wren-Lewis argues that while rational expectations may seem a strong assumption, the approach resembles that of microeconomics to other subjects: Firms may not know the true demand curves for their products, yet the assumption of profit-maximising prices may be a better approximation to how they choose prices than a model where they have a fixed mark-up on costs. So it also seems consistent to also assume that agents use relevant and available information to generate expectations when those expectations matter. And how else would one make sense of a whole forecasting industry, and the newsworthy character of macro forecasts?

Mark Thoma takes a measured view of rational expectations. On the one hand, it would be foolish to assume people didn’t use new information and purely extrapolated from past trends. Who would assume a trend will continue when there is good information saying otherwise? And one should think that people will react to announced changes in policies. On the other hand, it is quite a stretch to assume that people fully understand the policy rules used as well as how they will impact the economy.  Simplifications, rules of thumb or hard-wiring may explain quite a bit – e.g. why we can catch a ball in flight without solving complicated differential equations – and the correction of individual errors on markets may explain even something more, but it is to be doubted that it extends to fully approximating the functioning of complex markets. Rational expectations may be a good benchmark, just like the assumption of a perfect vacuum in physics, and may approximately hold in some contexts such as simple games and financial markets.  However, it would be a mistake to assume they apply universally.

Nick Rowe writes that one should expect people to use rules of thumb in reality. This is a rational strategy for individuals as long as the world is well approximated by the rule used. For any naive way of forming expectations, there exists a world in which that naive way of forming expectations would be rational. In a world where the price level followed a random walk – something like the Gold Standard world – the naive expectation of 0% inflation is rational. In a world where the price level followed a random walk plus 2% drift, roughly a 2% inflation target world, the naive expectation of 2% inflation would be rational. And if the inflation rate followed a random walk, the naive expectation that next period’s inflation rate would be the same as last period’s inflation rate would be rational. It’s when the world changes that things get tricky.  The naive expectations that were rational in the old world aren’t rational in the new world. This comes down to an argument for small c-conservatism in monetary policy rules and elsewhere in order to keep expectations rational for longer than they otherwise would be.

Expectations and data

Robert Waldmann points out that the Michigan Survey (inflation expectations of ordinary people) shows that inflation expectations are closely correlated to current CPI inflation – except when large external shocks such as oil price shocks occur. And in recent years, survey forecast inflation is persistently higher than actual inflation – while people’s estimates of current inflation also exceed actual figures. This does not seem in tune with rational expectations either and rather point towards backwards-looking expectation formation.

Source: Stumbling and Mumbling / Chris Dillow, using Bank of England data

Chris Dillow  points out that in the data, expected inflation and perceived inflation are strongly correlated. While this may be consistent with some rational expectations, it is also largely consistent with a simple rule of thumb: expect inflation to be what it is now, but adjust down if inflation is unusually high, and up if it’s unusually low. However, this rule of thumb does not seem to hold for exceptional circumstances. During the recession, inflation expectations were lower than those this rule of thumb would generate. Maybe, it is reasonable to suspect that inflation expectations are indeed formed by backward looking simple rules of thumb in normal times – but in exceptional times, people abandon rules of thumb for more complex processes as the costs of being wrong increase.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read article More on this topic
 

Blog Post

A world divided: global vaccine trade and production

COVID-19 has reinforced traditional vaccine production patterns, but the global vaccine trade has changed considerably.

By: Lionel Guetta-Jeanrenaud, Niclas Poitiers and Reinhilde Veugelers Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 20, 2021
Read article More on this topic
 

Opinion

Increasing the global supply of essential medical supplies: Time for Europe to step up its global leadership

Europe has already made a significant financial contribution to beating the pandemic, now it has the oppurtunity and moral responsibility to do more.

By: Anne Bucher and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 19, 2021
Read article More by this author
 

Blog Post

The European Union’s carbon border mechanism and the WTO

To avoid any backlash, the European Union should work with other World Trade Organisation members to define basic principles of carbon border adjustment mechanisms.

By: André Sapir Topic: Energy & Climate, Global Economics & Governance Date: July 19, 2021
Read article Download PDF
 

External Publication

Building the Road to Greener Pastures

How the G20 can support the recovery with sustainable local infrastructure investment.

By: Mia Hoffmann, Ben McWilliams and Niclas Poitiers Topic: Global Economics & Governance, Testimonies Date: July 15, 2021
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

Could the RMB dislodge the dollar as a reserve currency?

The dollar remains the world’s largest reserve currency, but it is facing both domestic and external risks.

By: Alicia García-Herrero Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 14, 2021
Read about event
 

Past Event

Past Event

Financing for Pandemic Preparedness and Response

How can we better prepare for future pandemics? In this event, co-hosted by the Center for Global Development and Bruegel think tanks, speakers will present "A Global Deal for Our Pandemic Age", a report of the G20 High Level Independent Panel on Financing the Global Commons for Pandemic Preparedness and Response.

Speakers: Masood Ahmed, Victor J. Dzau, Amanda Glassman and Lawrence H. Summers Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation, Global Economics & Governance Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: July 14, 2021
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Podcast

Podcast

What should public spending look like?

What should we do about the increase in public spending due to COVID-19? Bruegel Director Guntram Wolff and Former Deputy Secretary-General of OECD Ludger Schuknecht discuss.

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 14, 2021
Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

Sep
1
11:00

Resolving today’s global health crisis, and avoiding future pandemics

Bruegel Annual Meetings, Day 1- How do we exit the COVID-19 pandemic and ensure the world of tomorrow is less vulnerable to future pandemics?

Speakers: Jeremy Farrar, Amanda Glassman, Tharman Shanmugaratnam and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Global Economics & Governance Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels
Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

Sep
1
15:00

The future of EU-Africa relations

Bruegel Annual Meetings, Day 1 - A discussion of the state of play and outlook of EU-Africa relations.

Speakers: Masood Ahmed, Maria Demertzis, Amadou Hott, Vera Songwe and Jutta Urpilainen Topic: Global Economics & Governance Location: Palais des Academies, Rue Ducale 1
Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

Sep
2
16:00

Navigating a more polarised world: policy implications

Bruegel Annual Meetings, Day 2 - Are we entering a new age in the relationship between international economics and global politics? Is Europe well-equipped for this new world?

Speakers: Hélène Rey, Jean Pisani-Ferry, Adam Tooze and Sabine Weyand Topic: Global Economics & Governance Location: Palais des Academies, Rue Ducale 1
Read article More on this topic
 

External Publication

A Global Deal for Our Pandemic Age

Report of the G20 High Level Independent Panel on Financing the Global Commons for Pandemic Preparedness and Response.

By: Tharman Shanmugaratnam, Lawrence H. Summers, Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala, Ana Botin, Mohamed El-Erian, Jacob Frenkel, Rebeca Grynspan, Naoko Ishii, Michael Kremer, Kiran Mazumdar-Shaw, Luis Alberto Moreno, Lucrezia Reichlin, John-Arne Røttingen, Vera Songwe, Mark Suzman, Tidjane Thiam, Jean-Claude Trichet, Ngaire Woods, ZHU Min, Masood Ahmed, Guntram B. Wolff, Victor J. Dzau and Jeremy Farrar Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 9, 2021
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

Strengthening the weak links: future of supply chains

What new supply chains trends will we see in the post-pandemic era?

Speakers: Ebru Özdemir, André Sapir and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: July 7, 2021
Load more posts