Blog Post

Why Europe Struggles – And How it can Recover

Director Jean Pisani-Ferry addresses the questions about Europe’s structure, governance and competitiveness that arose from the financial crisis. Among them: Why was Europe hit so hard by the financial crisis? What does the crisis tell us about Europe’s internal challenges? How lasting and severe will the fiscal and consequences be? What is the agenda for […]

By: Date: January 11, 2010 Topic: Macroeconomic policy

Director Jean Pisani-Ferry addresses the questions about Europe’s structure, governance and competitiveness that arose from the financial crisis. Among them: Why was Europe hit so hard by the financial crisis? What does the crisis tell us about Europe’s internal challenges? How lasting and severe will the fiscal and consequences be? What is the agenda for financial reform?

As the European economy slowly emerges from the Great Recession of 2008-2009, questions abound that will occupy the minds require the energy of policymakers for many more months or possibly years: why was Europe hit so hard by the financial shock? What does the crisis tell us about Europe’s internal challenges? How lasting will its consequences be? How severe will its social consequences be? How serious will its fiscal consequences be – and how can they be contained? And finally, what is the agenda for financial reform? Let me take them one by one.
The crisis was not made in Europe, but so far at least, its consequences have been roughly as severe in Europe as in the US. This is a shocking fact that requires explanations. There are essentially three non-exclusive explanations. First, as the EU and the US financial sectors were deeply integrated, Europe’s banking system got paralysed exactly at the same time as its US counterpart. True, it is not Europe but China that financed the US current account deficit and accumulated dollar balances. But this had to do with net savings flows. In gross terms, Europe’s holdings of US securities at the beginning of 2007 dwarfed China’s (and furthermore it consisted much more in private securities such as corporate bonds and structured financial products whose value was directly affected by the consequences of the sub-prime crisis. Second, Europe had several internal weaknesses that were revealed by the crisis. First, the UK, Spain and Ireland had experienced a real estate boom of major magnitude and they were directly hit by the reversal of housing demand and prices. Second, several countries in the Mediterranean and the Central and Eastern region were running unsustainable current account over 10% of GDP that were financed by intra-EU savings flows (especially from Germany and other Northern European countries); the crisis gave the signal that time had come to adjust. Third, some counties, especially Germany, were very exposed to world trade, and were hit severely by its collapse. Together, these three factors help explain why there was a severe European crisis.
The same factors help explain why the recovery is still weak and why it will take time for the EU to recover fully. Unlike the US, Europe is a very bank-based economy, meaning that most companies rely on bank loans rather than on corporate paper markets to finance their investments. As long as some banks that have suffered significant losses (either on the US market or on their domestic real estate loan portfolio) have not rebuilt their capital base, they remain reluctant to lend, thereby putting a brake on the speed and the strength of the recovery. In spite of governments having moved swiftly to address the banks’ problems and prevent systemic failures, not all financial institutions have fully recognised the extent of the inevitable write-downs and some therefore remain under-capitalised. It is well known from the Japanese experience that ‘zombie banks’ are a real economic threat and this threat has not fully dissipated in Europe. In addition, Europe as a whole did not enter the crisis with a weak current account position and therefore that does not have to undergo a major macroeconomic adjustment (this is a significant difference with the US), several economies within it have to undergo such adjustments – away from consumption and deficit-financed booms, towards investment-led, domestically-financed and thereby sustainable growth, or away from finance
and real estate, towards new sectors whose nature is yet unknown. This is bound to weigh on their growth performance.
A weak recovery is having two consequences. First, unemployment is likely to increase significantly. Unlike the US, European companies did not respond to the crisis with major lay-offs. There were some exceptions (for example in Spain, where workers on temporary contracts were made redundant) but in general companies rater chose to keep their employees while putting them on reduced schedules or partial redundancy. Germany is the best example of such behaviour: thanks to a temporary reduced working time scheme subsidised by the government, there has been virtually no unemployment increase in spite of the country having suffered a 5% output decline in 2009. But absent a strong recovery, companies now need to start adjusting their payroll. This is especially the case in the traded goods sectors where European producers already struggle to remain competitive vis-à-vis US and Chinese producers in spite of the appreciation of the euro. The upshot is that the labour market will continue to deteriorate for some time. This is creating a politically untenable situation where workers see several banks returning to profit and giving out hefty bonuses while their own situation continues to deteriorate. Furthermore, weak or a delayed recovery means that laid-off workers and new entrants in the labour market will risk remaining idle for long, thereby losing their human capital if not exiting the labour force altogether. The second consequence of a weak recovery is that forgone investment will result in a lower capital stock when growth starts accelerating, thereby also making some of the temporary output loss permanent. Financial crises generally result in such permanent output losses and the fear in Europe is that it will be true this time too. So governments need to find out what kind of reforms they should conduct to minimise such permanent output losses but they also need to make contingent plans for the case they would turn out to be unavoidable. It is precisely the fear of such permanent output losses that is prompting discussion on the so-called ‘exit strategies’. Together with central banks, governments responded to the crisis with speed and force and they can be commended for this. But they have started worrying about the longer-term fiscal cost of the situation. It is not only the stimulus that needs to be withdrawn. In fact, it is generally a minor part of the problem. More significant are the forgone revenues – as governments sectors are large a 1% GDP loss roughly implies a 0.5% of GDP revenue loss – and the interest burden resulting from newly accumulated public debt. By the time the public debt ratios have stabilised they will have increased by some 30% of GDP or more, which implies for the medium term some 1.5% additional interest burden . So the magnitude of the fiscal adjustment that will need to be carried out has no precedent in recent decades. Financial markets have started realising this and they are getting nervous, as shown by the downgrading of the Greek government bonds’ ratings and the simultaneous rise of the interest rate spreads between Greece and Germany. Anxiety is part excessive. But it adds to preexisting concerns and pushes governments towards fiscal consolidation. It is now planned to start the budgetary adjustment in 2011 and to pursue it over several years (some smaller countries like Ireland or Hungary are starting in 2010 already). This is sensible, provided the recovery strengthens sufficiently in the meantime. If this is not the case by Summer 2010, when final budgets are presented to parliaments, European governments will be confronted to a delicate balancing act: either to proceed with the adjustment, at the risk of killing a feeble recovery; or to postpone it, at the risk of eliciting negative market reactions. Fears about the strength of the recovery and the priority justifiably given to budgetary adjustment over monetary normalisation means that interest rates are likely to remain very low for a long time. Even though the European Central Bank and the other central banks of the EU have started mopping up the huge amounts of liquidity they provided in Autumn 2008, they are bound to keep monetary policy supportive for at least the quarters to come. This entails the risk of creating conditions for financial instability through new asset price bubbles or carry trade among currency areas. To prevent them, the Europeans have decided to put in place a new framework for so-called ‘macro-prudential supervision’. In a nutshell, the idea is to make a new body consisting mainly of central bankers responsible for spotting threats to financial stability and for issuing warnings to financial supervisors and possibly also governments. The system is complex because it involves both EU and national authorities, and it is untested. But at least this is an attempt to draw the consequences from the crisis and to depart from the previously dominant attitude that gave priority to preserving national prerogatives in the field of supervision in spite of the growing integration of markets and financial institutions across countries. Time will tell whether it is the start of the building up of a new pan-European regulatory and supervisory architecture. To sum up, Europe is entering the new decade with both comfort and anxiety. Comfort, because the policy system it created at the end of the 1990s has passed an exceptionally severe stress test; anxiety, because several severe challenges remain. It is to be hoped that the former will help confront the latter.

(*) Jean Pisani-Ferry is the Director of Bruegel, the Brussels-based economic think tank

This column was published in Chinese business magazine Century Weekly.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Podcast

Podcast

Taming inflation?

What are the implications of prolonged inflation?

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: May 25, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

How can we support and restructure firms hit by the COVID-19 crisis?

What are the vulnerabilities and risks in the enterprise sector and how prepared are countries to handle a large-scale restructuring of businesses?

Speakers: Ceyla Pazarbasioglu and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 25, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

May - Jun
31-1
10:30

MICROPROD Final Event

Improving understanding of productivity, its drivers and the way we measure it.

Speakers: Carlo Altomonte, Eric Bartelsman, Marta Bisztray, Peter Bøegh Nielsen, Italo Colantone, Maria Demertzis, Wolfhard Kaus, Javier Miranda, Steffen Müller, Verena Plümpe, Niclas Poitiers, Andrea Roventini, Gianluca Santoni, Valerie Smeets, Nicola Viegi and Markus Zimmermann Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels
Read about event
 

Past Event

Past Event

[Cancelled] Shifting taxes in order to achieve green goals

[This event is cancelled until further notice] How could shifting the tax burden from labour to pollution and resources help the EU reach its climate goals?

Speakers: Niclas Poitiers and Femke Groothuis Topic: Green economy, Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 12, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

How are crises changing central bank doctrines?

How is monetary policy evolving in the face of recent crises? With central banks taking on new roles, how accountable are they to democratic institutions?

Speakers: Maria Demertzis, Benoît Coeuré, Pervenche Berès, Hans-Helmut Kotz and Athanasios Orphanides Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 11, 2022
Read article Download PDF More by this author
 

Book/Special report

European governanceInclusive growth

Bruegel annual report 2021

The Bruegel annual report provides a broad overview of the organisation's work in the previous year.

By: Bruegel Topic: Banking and capital markets, Digital economy and innovation, European governance, Global economy and trade, Green economy, Inclusive growth, Macroeconomic policy Date: May 6, 2022
Read article Download PDF
 

Policy Contribution

European governance

Fiscal support and monetary vigilance: economic policy implications of the Russia-Ukraine war for the European Union

Policymakers must think coherently about the joint implications of their actions, from sanctions on Russia to subsidies and transfers to their own citizens, and avoid taking measures that contradict each other. This is what we try to do in this Policy Contribution, focusing on the macroeconomic aspects of relevance for Europe.

By: Olivier Blanchard and Jean Pisani-Ferry Topic: European governance, Macroeconomic policy Date: April 29, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Working Paper

The low productivity of European firms: how can policies enhance the allocation of resources?

A summary of the most important policy lessons from research undertaken in the MICROPROD project work package 4, related to the allocation of the factors of production, with a special focus on the weak dynamism of European small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).

By: Grégory Claeys, Marie Le Mouel and Giovanni Sgaravatti Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 25, 2022
Read article More on this topic
 

External Publication

What drives implementation of the European Union’s policy recommendations to its member countries?

Article published in the Journal of Economic Policy Reform.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 13, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic More by this author
 

Working Paper

Measuring the intangible economy to address policy challenges

The purpose of the first work package of the MICROPROD project was to improve the firm-level data infrastructure, expand the measurement of intangible assets and enable cross-country analyses of these productivity trends.

By: Marie Le Mouel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 11, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

Macroeconomic and financial stability in changing times: conversation with Andrew Bailey

Guntram Wolff will be joined in conversation by Andrew Bailey, Governor of the Bank of England.

Speakers: Andrew Bailey and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: March 28, 2022
Read article
 

Opinion

European governance

How to reconcile increased green public investment needs with fiscal consolidation

The EU’s ambitious emissions reduction targets will require a major increase in green investments. This column considers options for increasing public green investment when major consolidations are needed after the fiscal support provided during the pandemic. The authors make the case for a green golden rule allowing green investment to be funded by deficits that would not count in the fiscal rules. Concerns about ‘greenwashing’ could be addressed through a narrow definition of green investments and strong institutional scrutiny, while countries with debt sustainability concerns could initially rely only on NGEU for their green investment.

By: Zsolt Darvas and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: European governance, Green economy, Macroeconomic policy Date: March 8, 2022
Load more posts