Blog Post

Only teamwork can put the Eurozone on a steady course

European policymakers returning to work after the summer recess are not being greeted with good news. In the post-referendum debate in June, the idea that emerged was that the voters in France and the Netherlands had primarily expressed dissatisfaction with Europe’s economic performance and that growth was needed to restore the European Union’s legitimacy. Yet […]

By: Date: August 29, 2005 Topic: Macroeconomic policy

European policymakers returning to work after the summer recess are not being greeted with good news. In the post-referendum debate in June, the idea that emerged was that the voters in France and the Netherlands had primarily expressed dissatisfaction with Europe’s economic performance and that growth was needed to restore the European Union’s legitimacy. Yet recently released statistics show that even before the recent hike in oil prices, growth in the EU as well as the eurozone barely exceeded 1 per cent.
Neither monetary nor fiscal policy can be expected to redress the situation. The eurozone’s aggregate budget deficit is approaching 3 per cent and the European Central Bank is now wary of potential second-round effects of the increase in oil prices. The consensus is therefore that, more than ever, growth can only be expected from structural reforms. There is, however, wide agreement that the Lisbon strategy adopted five years ago has not delivered the expected boost to reforms. Indicators confirm that economic reform in Europe has neither accelerated nor become more coordinated since 2000. In fact, Romain Duval and Jørgen Elmeskov of the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Development find in a recent paper that reform has slowed in the 2000s, especially in the eurozone.
The revamped Lisbon strategy adopted in spring by the European council to co-ordinate reforms is unlikely to deliver more. The set of objectives has been narrowed and the procedures streamlined but the strategy continues to lack incentives. If anything, the Commission’s new reluctance to “name and shame” the laggards has removed one of the few incentives that there were. EU member states may decide to reform on their own but the EU framework hardly matters. After all, the agenda 2010 of Gerhard Schröder, German chancellor, did not even refer to the EU strategy. Does it matter? The answer differs for the EU as a whole and for the eurozone. Assume for example, that country A undertakes reforms that lower structural unemployment and increase productivity, while another, B, does nothing. Reform in country A affects country B through trade channels but without diminishing the gains to country A. A permanent lowering in unemployment or a rise in productivity are benefits in their own right, whatever the consequences for the neighbours. Country B could also be affected as voters observe the effect of reform across the border and make decisions accordingly. To risk being followed by neighbours, however, does not reduce the incentive to reform. The upshot is that the rationale for co-ordinating reform policies within the EU is weak. There is nothing wrong in fostering policy learning and league tables, but there is not much to be expected from it. What about the eurozone? Let us again suppose A reforms and B does not.
Lower structural unemployment and higher productivity translate into lower inflation – at least temporarily – in country A, thereby lowering the average eurozone inflation rate. As the ECB targets inflation, this in turn translates into lower interest rates. Country B’s macroeconomic policy environment is thus modified by its neighbour’s policy. But average inflation and interest rates remain higher than if both countries had reformed or if country A had had monetary policy autonomy. For B’s government, there is a windfall. For A’s government, some of the benefits of reform are lost.
The difference with the EU case comes from the fact that eurozone countries share an interest rate that is set by the ECB with respect to the average inflation rate. This creates an interdependence that extends beyond the usual realm of monetary and fiscal policies and affects structural policies too. This interdependence matters especially for measures that are costly in the short run, because a lower interest rate can help to offset their adverse effects and improve their overall balance. This is the case of many reforms. Labour market reforms may increase unemployment before they lower it because they create anxiety and lead firm to shed labour faster than they create new jobs. Product market reforms may also depress growth because incumbents react immediately to the loss of rents while entry only develops over time. This is why reform is easier when accompanied by monetary expansion (to offset the negative effects of reform on aggregate demand) and fiscal stimulus (which also helps to compensate the losers). This kind of strategy can be followed outside the eurozone, not within it – unless reforms are co-ordinated.
The conclusion is twofold. First, the case for co-ordinating reform policies is weak for the EU as a whole but stronger for the eurozone. Second, reform in the eurozone would benefit from being able to rely on macroeconomic support. The EU started taking these requirements into account in last spring’s reform
of the stability and growth pact. It is now accepted that growth-enhancing reforms can be a motive for temporarily deviating from the “close to balance” target the members are committed to, or for delaying the convergence towards it. Although this provision does not give much additional margin of manoeuvre to the big-deficit countries, it is a step in the right direction.
More is required. First, the institutional framework needs to be adapted. The eurozone finance ministers who meet in the eurogroup do not set the reform agenda. The heads of government who are in charge of that agenda never meet in eurozone format. Neither do the labour or economy ministers. A eurozone meeting of the heads of government would remind them of their responsibility for the sustainability of the currency area they have created, and would allow them to discuss their reform agendas and confront the effects of their interdependance.
The other change concerns the ECB. The Central Bank is long on exhortations but short on commitments. It should explicitly state that, without prejudice to price stability, it will back reforms that lower structural unemployment or put the eurozone on a higher growth path. ECB officials have already acknowledged the complementarities between monetary policy and structural reforms and have hinted at the additional room of manoeuvre that the latter would create for monetary policy. The ECB should go further and unequivocally recognise that, provided that governments act, monetary policy would be able to support their action. Such a promise would involve a risk. The question, however, is whether it is preferable to take the alternative risk of remaining in a deadlock that would ultimately undermine the sustainability of the monetary union.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

May
25
14:30

How can we support and restructure firms hit by the COVID-19 crisis?

What are the vulnerabilities and risks in the enterprise sector and how prepared are countries to handle a large-scale restructuring of businesses?

Speakers: Ceyla Pazarbasioglu and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy
Read about event
 

Past Event

Past Event

[Cancelled] Shifting taxes in order to achieve green goals

[This event is cancelled until further notice] How could shifting the tax burden from labour to pollution and resources help the EU reach its climate goals?

Speakers: Niclas Poitiers and Femke Groothuis Topic: Green economy, Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 12, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

How are crises changing central bank doctrines?

How is monetary policy evolving in the face of recent crises? With central banks taking on new roles, how accountable are they to democratic institutions?

Speakers: Maria Demertzis, Benoît Coeuré, Pervenche Berès, Hans-Helmut Kotz and Athanasios Orphanides Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels Date: May 11, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Upcoming Event

May - Jun
31-1
10:30

MICROPROD Final Event

Final conference of the MICROPROD project

Speakers: Carlo Altomonte, Eric Bartelsman, Marta Bisztray, Italo Colantone, Maria Demertzis, Filippo di Mauro, Wolfhard Kaus, Steffen Müller, Gianluca Santoni, Verena Plümpe, Andrea Roventini, Valerie Smeets, Nicola Viegi, Markus Zimmermann and Javier Miranda Topic: Macroeconomic policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels
Read article Download PDF More by this author
 

Book/Special report

European governanceInclusive growth

Bruegel annual report 2021

The Bruegel annual report provides a broad overview of the organisation's work in the previous year.

By: Bruegel Topic: Banking and capital markets, Digital economy and innovation, European governance, Global economy and trade, Green economy, Inclusive growth, Macroeconomic policy Date: May 6, 2022
Read article Download PDF
 

Policy Contribution

European governance

Fiscal support and monetary vigilance: economic policy implications of the Russia-Ukraine war for the European Union

Policymakers must think coherently about the joint implications of their actions, from sanctions on Russia to subsidies and transfers to their own citizens, and avoid taking measures that contradict each other. This is what we try to do in this Policy Contribution, focusing on the macroeconomic aspects of relevance for Europe.

By: Olivier Blanchard and Jean Pisani-Ferry Topic: European governance, Macroeconomic policy Date: April 29, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic
 

Working Paper

The low productivity of European firms: how can policies enhance the allocation of resources?

A summary of the most important policy lessons from research undertaken in the MICROPROD project work package 4, related to the allocation of the factors of production, with a special focus on the weak dynamism of European small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).

By: Grégory Claeys, Marie Le Mouel and Giovanni Sgaravatti Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 25, 2022
Read article More on this topic
 

External Publication

What drives implementation of the European Union’s policy recommendations to its member countries?

Article published in the Journal of Economic Policy Reform.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 13, 2022
Read article Download PDF More on this topic More by this author
 

Working Paper

Measuring the intangible economy to address policy challenges

The purpose of the first work package of the MICROPROD project was to improve the firm-level data infrastructure, expand the measurement of intangible assets and enable cross-country analyses of these productivity trends.

By: Marie Le Mouel Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: April 11, 2022
Read about event More on this topic
 

Past Event

Past Event

Macroeconomic and financial stability in changing times: conversation with Andrew Bailey

Guntram Wolff will be joined in conversation by Andrew Bailey, Governor of the Bank of England.

Speakers: Andrew Bailey and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: March 28, 2022
Read article
 

Opinion

European governance

How to reconcile increased green public investment needs with fiscal consolidation

The EU’s ambitious emissions reduction targets will require a major increase in green investments. This column considers options for increasing public green investment when major consolidations are needed after the fiscal support provided during the pandemic. The authors make the case for a green golden rule allowing green investment to be funded by deficits that would not count in the fiscal rules. Concerns about ‘greenwashing’ could be addressed through a narrow definition of green investments and strong institutional scrutiny, while countries with debt sustainability concerns could initially rely only on NGEU for their green investment.

By: Zsolt Darvas and Guntram B. Wolff Topic: European governance, Green economy, Macroeconomic policy Date: March 8, 2022
Read article More on this topic More by this author
 

Opinion

The week inflation became entrenched

The events that have unfolded since 24 February have solved one dispute: inflation is no longer temporary.

By: Maria Demertzis Topic: Macroeconomic policy Date: March 8, 2022
Load more posts